Saturday, December 11, 2010

Surviving Uncertain Times
 
Dec 1st 2010, C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh
There's really no question about it: the world economy is heading for a period of great economic uncertainty, in which instability, trade and currency conflicts and possibilities of economic stagnation all loom large. This reflects the absence of a global economic leader willing and able to fulfil the roles identified by Charles Kindleberger: discounting in crisis; countercyclical lending to countries affected by private investors' decisions; and providing a market for net exports of the rest of the world, especially those countries requiring it to repay debt. For obvious reasons, the US cannot currently do these, and there is no evident alternative. That is why co-ordination is so critical right now for international capitalism, and why its absence will definitely be felt.
Governments of both developed and developing countries seem to be caught between the (often self-imposed) rock of fiscal consolidation created by the hysteria of bond market vigilantes and the financial media, and the hard place created by the unwillingness to give up what is clearly an outdated growth model. As a result, we are faced with the worst of all economic outcomes in terms of socially fraught stagnation in the North and ecologically destructive and fragile expansion in the South, with workers everywhere getting even worse off than before.

There are three major imbalances that continue to characterise the global economy: the imbalance between finance and the real economy; the macroeconomic imbalances between major economies; and the ecological imbalance created by the pattern of economic growth. While these are obviously unsustainable, the very process of their correction will necessarily have adverse effects on current growth trajectories.

As it happens, the US current account deficit is already under correction: the current account deficit in 2009 was just above half its 2008 level, and the data for this year suggest that it will stay at around that level. For the rest of the world, it does not really matter whether the reduction occurs through currency movements or trade protectionism or domestic economic contraction: the point is that some other engine of growth has to be found.

Curiously, the governments of the major economies in the global system, including G20, do not seem to have grasped this. The rather obvious point that all countries cannot use net export growth as the route to expansion does not seem to have been understood; so, all governments think they can export their way out of trouble. This will have inevitable implications for trade and currency wars, and the likelihood of global economic stagnation.

So, how well is the Indian economy likely to cope in the near future, and how will the population as a whole fare in these uncertain times? There has been much celebration in the financial media in India about how well we have weathered the Great Recession, and certainly the output indicators (Chart 1) are impressive in the overall global context. Despite poor agricultural performance, rates of growth of aggregate GDP have remained high because of continued high growth in services and significantly accelerated growth of industry (dominantly manufacturing).

Chart 1 >>

However, the recent pattern of growth has in general been so heavily skewed towards certain services that it has created an apparently unbalanced economy (Chart 2). Agriculture and other primary activities account for less than 15 per cent of GDP, even though they continue to employ well over half the workforce in what is obviously mostly low-productivity activity. Manufacturing has remained stable, and relatively small in output and even smaller in employment. However, the newer services that now dominate the GDP do not employ too many people either, so that most other workers are engaged in low remuneration services. Meanwhile, the FIRE sector (finance, insurance, real estate, and business services) has been growing rapidly and now accounts for an even higher share of GDP than manufacturing – a sure sign of a bubble economy.

Chart 2 >>
So this means that we are back to the same unsustainable pattern of growth that generated the images of ''India shining'': booms in retail credit sparked by financial deregulation and enabled by capital inflows. These have been combined, especially in the wake of the global crisis, with fiscal concessions to spur consumption among the richest sections of the population. This has generated a substantial rise in profit shares in the economy and the proliferation of financial activities, and combined with rising asset values to enable a continuation of the credit-financed consumption splurge among the rich and the middle classes along with debt-financed housing investment.

The problem is that this is associated with a balance of payments trajectory that is fundamentally unsustainable. As Chart 3 shows, it is only the invisibles account (led by remittances from India workers abroad and software and related exports) that has kept the balance of payments from appearing to be even more stark. The trade account shows ever growing deficits, which are increasingly driven by non-oil imports. Meanwhile, the large inflows of capital are really being stored up in the form of foreign exchange reserves, for fear of causing excessive exchange rate appreciation.

Chart 3 >>

In fact, after a brief period of reduction, India's place as a currently favoured destination for internationally mobile capital was reinforced in the past year. Chart 4 shows how different elements of the captial account have behaved in recent years. The most rapid post-crisis recovery has been in portfolio capital, which fell during the crisis year but surged back to high levels the subsequent year. In fact, the most recent data (not covered in this chart) indicates a troublesome surge in such hot money inflows, of more than $70 billion in just a few months – troublesome because it can lead to an unwanted currency appreciation and because it can just as easily flow out again.
This is a problem plaguing several emerging economies, and underlines the need for capital controls to prevent unwanted inflows of speculative capital. So much so that even the IMF has started advocating such controls for developing countries that are being swamped by the ''carry trade'' based on interest rate differentials across economies.
Chart 4 >>   

Unfortunately, our own government seems much less consious of the dangers such inflows pose, especially for an economy that is clearly in the midst of another bubble-driven expansion. Instead, Ministers are talking about the economy being able to absorb at least another $100 billion of capital inflows – unmindful of the reality that the economy has not even absorbed the smaller amounts that are currently pouring in, and instead is simply accumulating reserves.
In any case, such absorption has to be sustainable, which is why much more attention is required to improving the trade account. This is going to be much more difficult in the current global economy, but clearly the need is for both diversification of trade and more attention to sustainable expansion of the domestic market.

The good news is that on the external trade front there does seem to have been a significant process of diversification in the past decade, as Charts 5 and 6 indicate. China is among our largest trading partners now, though that dominantly consists of India exporting raw materials and intermediates and importing finished goods from China. The Middle East has also emerged as a major market, and other areas are playing increasing roles as well.

Chart 5 >>         Chart 6 >>

However, without sustained expansion of the domestic market, the condition of the bulk of the Indian population will not improve. This really requires increasing the disposable incomes of wage earners and the self-employed, not just a credit-based expansion of demand that is bound to end in tears. But for this, there has to be more official focus on generating both employment and better remuneration. This is actually quite doable, since it can be led by increased public provision of essential goods and services (all of which are employment generating and have high multiplier effects). But for that, we need genuine political will.                                              

COURTESY : MACROSAN.ORG

No comments:

Post a Comment